Debunking the `Tragedy of the Commons'

Moderators: Elvis, DrVolin, Jeff

Debunking the `Tragedy of the Commons'

Postby MacCruiskeen » Thu Aug 28, 2008 10:53 am

Via Ran Prieur:

[url=http://links.org.au/node/595]Debunking the `Tragedy of the Commons'

By Ian Angus[/url]

August 24, 2008 -- Will shared resources always be misused and overused? Is community ownership of land, forests and fisheries a guaranteed road to ecological disaster? Is privatisation the only way to protect the environment and end Third World poverty? Most economists and development planners will answer “yes” — and for proof they will point to the most influential article ever written on those important questions.

Since its publication in Science in December 1968, “The Tragedy of the Commons” has been anthologised in at least 111 books, making it one of the most-reprinted articles ever to appear in any scientific journal. It is also one of the most quoted: a recent Google search found “about 302,000” results for the phrase “tragedy of the commons”.

For 40 years it has been, in the words of a World Bank discussion paper, “the dominant paradigm within which social scientists assess natural resource issues” (Bromley and Cernea 1989: 6). It has been used time and again to justify stealing indigenous peoples’ lands, privatising health care and other social services, giving corporations ``tradable permits'' to pollute the air and water, and much more.

Noted anthropologist Dr G.N. Appell (1995) writes that the article “has been embraced as a sacred text by scholars and professionals in the practice of designing futures for others and imposing their own economic and environmental rationality on other social systems of which they have incomplete understanding and knowledge”.

Like most sacred texts, “The Tragedy of the Commons” is more often cited than read. As we will see, although its title sounds authoritative and scientific, it fell far short of science.

Garrett Hardin hatches a myth

The author of “The Tragedy of the Commons” was Garrett Hardin, a University of California professor who until then was best known as the author of a biology textbook that argued for “control of breeding” of “genetically defective” people (Hardin 1966: 707). In his 1968 essay he argued that communities that share resources inevitably pave the way for their own destruction; instead of wealth for all, there is wealth for none.

He based his argument on a story about the commons in rural England.

(The term “commons” was used in England to refer to the shared pastures, fields, forests, irrigation systems and other resources that were found in many rural areas until well into the 1800s. Similar communal farming arrangements existed in most of Europe, and they still exist today in various forms around the world, particularly in indigenous communities.)

“Picture a pasture open to all”, Hardin wrote. Herders who want to expand their personal herd will calculate that the cost of additional grazing (reduced food for all animals, rapid soil depletion) will be divided among all, but they alone will get the benefit of having more cattle to sell.

Inevitably, “the rational herdsman concludes that the only sensible course for him to pursue is to add another animal to his herd”. But every “rational herdsman” will do the same thing, so the commons is soon overstocked and overgrazed to the point where it supports no animals at all.

Hardin used the word “tragedy” as Aristotle did, to refer to a dramatic outcome that is the inevitable but unplanned result of a character’s actions. He called the destruction of the commons through overuse a tragedy not because it is sad, but because it is the inevitable result of shared use of the pasture. “Freedom in a commons brings ruin to all.”

Where’s the evidence?

Given the subsequent influence of Hardin’s essay, it’s shocking to realise that he provided no evidence at all to support his sweeping conclusions. He claimed that the “tragedy” was inevitable — but he didn’t show that it had happened even once.

Hardin simply ignored what actually happens in a real commons: self-regulation by the communities involved. One such process was described years earlier in Friedrich Engels’ account of the “mark”, the form taken by commons-based communities in parts of pre-capitalist Germany:

“[T]he use of arable and meadowlands was under the supervision and direction of the community …

“Just as the share of each member in so much of the mark as was distributed was of equal size, so was his share also in the use of the ‘common mark’. The nature of this use was determined by the members of the community as a whole. …

“At fixed times and, if necessary, more frequently, they met in the open air to discuss the affairs of the mark and to sit in judgment upon breaches of regulations and disputes concerning the mark.” (Engels 1892)

Historians and other scholars have broadly confirmed Engels’ description of communal management of shared resources. A summary of recent research concludes:

“[W]hat existed in fact was not a ‘tragedy of the commons’ but rather a triumph: that for hundreds of years — and perhaps thousands, although written records do not exist to prove the longer era — land was managed successfully by communities.” (Cox 1985: 60)

Part of that self-regulation process was known in England as “stinting” — establishing limits for the number of cows, pigs, sheep and other livestock that each commoner could graze on the common pasture. Such “stints” protected the land from overuse (a concept that experienced farmers understood long before Hardin arrived) and allowed the community to allocate resources according to its own concepts of fairness.

The only significant cases of overstocking found by the leading modern expert on the English commons involved wealthy landowners who deliberately put too many animals onto the pasture in order to weaken their much poorer neighbours’ position in disputes over the enclosure (privatisation) of common lands (Neeson 1993: 156).

Hardin assumed that peasant farmers are unable to change their behaviour in the face of certain disaster. But in the real world, small farmers, fishers and others have created their own institutions and rules for preserving resources and ensuring that the commons community survived through good years and bad.

Why does the herder want more?

Hardin’s argument started with the unproven assertion that herders always want to expand their herds: “It is to be expected that each herdsman will try to keep as many cattle as possible on the commons… As a rational being, each herdsman seeks to maximize his gain.”

In short, Hardin’s conclusion was predetermined by his assumptions. “It is to be expected” that each herder will try to maximise the size of their herd — and each one does exactly that. It’s a circular argument that proves nothing.

Hardin assumed that human nature is selfish and unchanging, and that society is just an assemblage of self-interested individuals who don’t care about the impact of their actions on the community. The same idea, explicitly or implicitly, is a fundamental component of mainstream (i.e. pro-capitalist) economic theory.

All the evidence (not to mention commonsense) shows that this is absurd: people are social beings, and society is much more than the arithmetic sum of its members. Even capitalist society, which rewards the most anti-social behaviour, has not crushed human cooperation and solidarity. The very fact that for centuries “rational herdsmen” did not overgraze the commons disproves Hardin’s most fundamental assumptions — but that hasn’t stopped him or his disciples from erecting policy castles on foundations of sand.

Even if the herder wanted to behave as Hardin described, they couldn’t do so unless certain conditions existed.

There would have to be a market for the cattle, and herders would have to be focused on producing for that market, not for local consumption. The herder would have to have enough capital to buy the additional cattle and the fodder they would need in winter. The herder would have to be able to hire workers to care for the larger herd, build bigger barns, etc. And the herder's desire for profit would have to outweigh their interest in the long-term survival of their community.

In short, Hardin didn’t describe the behaviour of herders in pre-capitalist farming communities — he described the behaviour of capitalists operating in a capitalist economy. The universal human nature that he claimed would always destroy common resources is actually the profit-driven “grow or die” behaviour of corporations.

Will private ownership do better?

That leads us to another fatal flaw in Hardin’s argument: in addition to providing no evidence that maintaining the commons will inevitably destroy the environment, he offered no justification for his opinion that privatisation would save it. Once again he simply presented his own prejudices as fact:

“We must admit that our legal system of private property plus inheritance is unjust — but we put up with it because we are not convinced, at the moment, that anyone has invented a better system. The alternative of the commons is too horrifying to contemplate. Injustice is preferable to total ruin.”

The implication is that private owners will do a better job of caring for the environment because they want to preserve the value of their assets. In reality, scholars and activists have documented scores of cases in which the division and privatisation of communally managed lands had disastrous results. Privatising the commons has repeatedly led to deforestation, soil erosion and depletion, overuse of fertilisers and pesticides, and the ruin of ecosystems.

As Karl Marx wrote, nature requires long cycles of birth, development and regeneration, but capitalism requires short-term returns.

“[T]he entire spirit of capitalist production, which is oriented towards the most immediate monetary profits, stands in contradiction to agriculture, which has to concern itself with the whole gamut of permanent conditions of life required by the chain of human generations. A striking illustration of this is furnished by the forests, which are only rarely managed in a way more or less corresponding to the interests of society as a whole …” (Marx 1998: 611n)

Contrary to Hardin’s claims, a community that shares fields and forests has a strong incentive to protect them to the best of its ability, even if that means not maximising current production, because those resources will be essential to the community’s survival for centuries to come. Capitalist owners have the opposite incentive, because they will not survive in business if they don’t maximise short-term profit. If ethanol promises bigger and faster profits than centuries-old rain forests, the trees will fall.

This focus on short-term gain has reached a point of appalling absurdity in recent best-selling books by Bjorn Lomborg, William Nordhaus and others, who argue that it is irrational to spend money to stop greenhouse gas emissions today, because the payoff is too far in the future. Other investments, they say, will produce much better returns, more quickly.

Community management isn’t an infallible way of protecting shared resources: some communities have mismanaged common resources, and some commons may have been overused to extinction. But no commons-based community has capitalism’s built-in drive to put current profits ahead of the wellbeing of future generations.

A politically useful myth

The truly appalling thing about “The Tragedy of the Commons” is not its lack of evidence or logic — badly researched and argued articles are not unknown in academic journals. What’s shocking is the fact that this piece of reactionary nonsense has been hailed as a brilliant analysis of the causes of human suffering and environmental destruction, and adopted as a basis for social policy by supposed experts ranging from economists and environmentalists to governments and United Nations agencies.

Despite being refuted again and again, it is still used today to support private ownership and uncontrolled markets as sure-fire roads to economic growth.

The success of Hardin’s argument reflects its usefulness as a pseudo-scientific explanation of global poverty and inequality, an explanation that doesn’t question the dominant social and political order. It confirms the prejudices of those in power: logical and factual errors are nothing compared to the very attractive (to the rich) claim that the poor are responsible for their own poverty. The fact that Hardin’s argument also blames the poor for ecological destruction is a bonus.

Hardin’s essay has been widely used as an ideological response to anti-imperialist movements in the Third World and discontent among indigenous and other oppressed peoples everywhere in the world.

“Hardin’s fable was taken up by the gathering forces of neo-liberal reaction in the 1970s, and his essay became the ‘scientific’ foundation of World Bank and IMF policies, viz. enclosure of commons and privatisation of public property. … The message is clear: we must never treat the earth as a ‘common treasury.’ We must be ruthless and greedy or else we will perish.” (Boal 2007)

In Canada, conservative lobbyists use arguments derived from Hardin’s political tract to explain away poverty on First Nations’ [Indigenous Canadians'] reserves, and to argue for further dismantling of Indigenous communities. A study published by the influential Fraser Institute urges privatisation of reserve land:

“[T]hese large amounts of land, with their attendant natural resources, will never yield their maximum benefit to Canada’s native people as long as they are held as collective property subject to political management. … collective property is the path of poverty, and private property is the path of prosperity.” (Fraser 2002: 16-17)

This isn’t just right-wing posturing. Canada’s federal government, which has refused to sign the United Nations Declaration on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples, announced in 2007 that it will “develop approaches to support the development of individual property ownership on reserves”, and created a C$300 million fund to do just that.

In Hardin’s world, poverty has nothing to do with centuries of racism, colonialism and exploitation: poverty is inevitable and natural in all times and places, the product of immutable human nature. The poor bring it on themselves by having too many babies and clinging to self-destructive collectivism.

The tragedy of the commons is a useful political myth — a scientific-sounding way of saying that there is no alternative to the dominant world order.

Stripped of excess verbiage, Hardin’s essay asserted, without proof, that human beings are helpless prisoners of biology and the market. Unless restrained, we will inevitably destroy our communities and environment for a few extra pennies of profit. There is nothing we can do to make the world better or more just.

In 1844 Friedrich Engels described a similar argument as a “repulsive blasphemy against man and nature”. Those words apply with full force to the myth of the tragedy of the commons.

[Ian Angus is editor of Climate and Capitalism and an associate editor of Socialist Voice, where this article first appeared.]

Citations and references here.
"Ich kann gar nicht so viel fressen, wie ich kotzen möchte." - Max Liebermann,, Berlin, 1933

"Science is the belief in the ignorance of experts." - Richard Feynman, NYC, 1966

TESTDEMIC ➝ "CASE"DEMIC
User avatar
MacCruiskeen
 
Posts: 10558
Joined: Thu Nov 16, 2006 6:47 pm
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby Endomorph » Thu Aug 28, 2008 12:11 pm

Out. Freaking. Standing.

See also: everything Alfie Kohn has ever written.
Endomorph
 
Posts: 154
Joined: Mon Mar 31, 2008 3:39 pm
Blog: View Blog (0)


Postby MacCruiskeen » Thu Aug 28, 2008 12:37 pm

Endomorph and Jeff, you're welcome. I think it's an outstanding piece. Harding's essay has been enormously influential, and I have to confess it disturbed me for years and actually convinced me for a while. (Not for a long while, though.) We live and learn. And Ian Angus has done something important there.
"Ich kann gar nicht so viel fressen, wie ich kotzen möchte." - Max Liebermann,, Berlin, 1933

"Science is the belief in the ignorance of experts." - Richard Feynman, NYC, 1966

TESTDEMIC ➝ "CASE"DEMIC
User avatar
MacCruiskeen
 
Posts: 10558
Joined: Thu Nov 16, 2006 6:47 pm
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby MacCruiskeen » Thu Aug 28, 2008 12:45 pm

Winstanley was a hero, and a fantastic writer:

"Not a full year since, being quiet at my work, my heart was filled with sweet thoughts... That the earth shall be made a common treasury of livlihood to whole mankind, without respect of persons; yet my mind was not at rest, because nothing was acted, and thoughts run in me that words and writings were all nothing and must die, for action is the life of all, and if thou dost not act, thou dost nothing."

Gerrard Winstanley: A Watch-Word to the City of London, and the Armie (August 26, 1649)


"[B]y the one they deceive the souls of people, for they preach the letter of the Spirit, and by the other they pick their purses. (...) Those writings which they live by, were not writings that proceeded produced from any Schollars, according to humane art, but from Fishermen, Shepherds, Husbandmen, and the Carpenters son, who spake and writ as the Spirit gave them utterance, from an inward testimony. Yet now these learned schollars have got the writings of these inferior men of the world so called, do now slight, despise and trample them under feet, pressing upon the powers of the earth, to make laws to hold them under bondage, and that lay-people, trades-men, and such as are not bred in schools, may have no liberty to speak or write of the Spirit. And why so? Because out of these despised ones, doth the spirit rise up more and more to clearer light, making them to speak from experience

(....) But now the learned schollars having no inward testimony of their own to uphold their trade by a customary practice, they hold fast the old letter, getting their living by telling the people the meanings of those trades-mens words and writings; but alas, they mightily corrupt their meaning, by their multitude of false expositions and interpretations; for no man knows the meaning of the spirit, but he hath the spirit."

- Gerrard Winstanley: The New Law of Righteousness
Last edited by MacCruiskeen on Thu Aug 28, 2008 12:48 pm, edited 2 times in total.
"Ich kann gar nicht so viel fressen, wie ich kotzen möchte." - Max Liebermann,, Berlin, 1933

"Science is the belief in the ignorance of experts." - Richard Feynman, NYC, 1966

TESTDEMIC ➝ "CASE"DEMIC
User avatar
MacCruiskeen
 
Posts: 10558
Joined: Thu Nov 16, 2006 6:47 pm
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby Jeff » Thu Aug 28, 2008 12:46 pm

MacCruiskeen wrote:I have to confess it disturbed me for years and actually convinced me for a while.


Me too. It's a persuasive argument because it contains elements of truth, but it can be used to pervert the best intentions towards an unnatural and inhuman place.
User avatar
Jeff
Site Admin
 
Posts: 11134
Joined: Fri Oct 20, 2000 8:01 pm
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby Endomorph » Thu Aug 28, 2008 12:55 pm

Thanks! I only knew that as a Billy Bragg song!
Endomorph
 
Posts: 154
Joined: Mon Mar 31, 2008 3:39 pm
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby Brentos » Thu Aug 28, 2008 3:19 pm

Good article, and thank you for the Winstanley quotes.

Regarding IMF & World Bank policies, this video is informative and very powerful, but also shows hope for the commons. Argentina's Economic Collapse

A perverse piece of propaganda targeting Liberals & The Left is on Ray Kurzweil's AI site. Its none other than the Unabomber Manifesto. Kurzweil has it on his site as a persuasive counter-argument to his views that technology will enhance man. As well as Luddite views that technology will be used to enslave man, the manifesto also contains a fair amount of strong psychological criticism of the Left and their 'oversocialization'. That liberals who take up causes like civil rights and helping the poor are doing so due to the mental problems that occur with oversocialization, rather than any innate goodness. These mental defects are due to people who have lost 'The Power Process' thanks to oversocialization which is supposedly central to the human being, the quest for power and having goals to attain that power. quote:

"Human beings have a need (probably based in biology) for something that we will call the "power process." This is closely related to the need for power (which is widely recognized) but is not quite the same thing. The power process has four elements. The three most clear-cut of these we call goal, effort and attainment of goal. (Everyone needs to have goals whose attainment requires effort, and needs to succeed in attaining at least some of his goals.) The fourth element is more difficult to define and may not be necessary for everyone. We call it autonomy and will discuss it later "

http://www.kurzweilai.net/meme/frame.ht ... t0182.html

randian-eqsue indeed.

It contains some convincing arguments, yet reading the article is very disturbing, and is full of 1/2 truths. On the internets, there are some sites which say that the manifesto was not penned, or only partially penned by Ted Kaczynski.
User avatar
Brentos
 
Posts: 515
Joined: Thu Dec 21, 2006 5:01 pm
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby Penguin » Thu Aug 28, 2008 4:39 pm

Thanks, great one!
That tragedy of the commons crap is taught in our university economics classes, today... Economics 101 - How to Piss yourself and others in Both Eyes.
Penguin
 
Posts: 5089
Joined: Thu Aug 23, 2007 5:56 pm
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby Searcher08 » Thu Aug 28, 2008 6:56 pm

Jeff wrote:
MacCruiskeen wrote:I have to confess it disturbed me for years and actually convinced me for a while.


Me too. It's a persuasive argument because it contains elements of truth, but it can be used to pervert the best intentions towards an unnatural and inhuman place.


I had not realised that there was a political background to this, as it is an example of a certain structure that often occurs within organisations and which has nothing to do with human nature or politics, but autonomy, communication and collaboration issues.

I have seen this structure in lots of corporates in relation to the computer department, where the computer department is a service department and other departments are services users. These other departments may have little to do with each other and little cooperation. They each use as much of the IT department as they need to improve their own departments performance as much as they can. Eventually the IT department reaches the stage of collapse through over commitment / staff burn-out / computer bottlenecks etc which then impacts the departments - the IT service users and hits *their* performance.

The solution to this problem is systemic - it is a feedback from each of the departments into the resource limit of the IT department, so the success of the service users helps create more resource for everyone - a virtuous circle.

Many service users will have forums that seek to engineer these type of feedback loops in an organic way.

Interestingly, the other approach to solving this structure is MUCH less effective - that is the imposition of an outside control structure which 'polices' the departments to keep to a specific level of resource usage - this sounds like the Big Brother-oriented approach adopted in the article. In general it leads to unending 'resource contention' where huge amounts of the systems energy falls down the plughole of 'pitching' for a 'fair share' of limited resources (I'm being kind - it's more like kids throwing tantrums over the relative size of their slice of their cake)

It was interesting to read the example from Engels from an organisational design point of view, as the community itself had self-organised the feedback loops needed to address the problem.
User avatar
Searcher08
 
Posts: 5887
Joined: Thu Dec 20, 2007 10:21 am
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby sfnate » Thu Aug 28, 2008 7:39 pm

Excellent article. Thanks for posting.

As a libertarian socialist, I am continually frustrated by my libertarian cousins' insistence that a free, unregulated market combined with comprehensive privatization equals some kind of economic nirvana that will solve any manner of problems, societal and environmental. Of course, I understand and am sympathetic to their zealous defense of individual liberties--of course--but the quasi-religious devotion to the "invisible hand" I find deeply disturbing, simply because it is an awkward and irreconcilable marriage of economic rationalism with capitalist mysticism. As is the case in most religious arguments, there's nothing that will persuade them that their chosen faith contains troubling contradictions--but then again I suppose that is true of most religions.
User avatar
sfnate
 
Posts: 124
Joined: Thu Jun 28, 2007 4:51 pm
Location: Le Grand Fossard
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby exojuridik » Fri Aug 29, 2008 1:54 am

This tragedy is also taught in 1L property law classes as a way to show how rationalized self-interest through the legal system can more efficiently maintain the "common good." However, there is nothing wrong with this using this approach to highlight the dilemma of individual actors attempting to maintain their mutual interests in a situation where acting toward their short-term gains undermines their collective and long-term good. From a game-theoretical stand point this can only be resolved through a form of a Nash equilibrium state where all the actors forgo their primary goal and adopt a strategy of satisficing and accept less in the short term so that they may achieve their long-term interests. The problem that arises is one common to all cooperative strategies - namely the prisoner dilemma where actors must coordinate their actions while stuck in an informational vacuum i.e. how can I trust my neighbor not to sell me down the proverbial river.

The solution to this problem in its many facets has been institutional. Create an enforcement regime that will ensure that the all the actors behave in a manner salubrious to the stated good e.g. international trade regimes, environmental agreements, multilateral treaties etc . . . In a multipolar world this can be more or less achieved by demonstrating that defecting or opting out of this regime will cost the player more than it will benefit them. The genius of the post-WWII system established by the Anglo-American alliance (see Brettonwoods agreement etc . . .) was that the big players used these regimes to create a reasonablely stable financial and political system that endured throughout the cold war. Thus the Europeans and Americans could run the world mainly by inducements rather than threats - the new world order indeed. (unfortunately the man largely responsible for its logic was driven mad by the CIA/aliens/demon overlords.)

The problem that is now confronting the planet is that the big players, the one capable of maintaining the enforcement regime- Russia, china, the US, are the ones defecting and going it alone. In my mind that is the difference between Obama/Clintons and Cheney/Putin/neocons. The former are tied to interests being benefitted by the game (hi-tech, banking, environmentalists), while the latter are benefitted by a far darker game of leviathons and wars and rumors of wars.

There is no opting out of the game itself - rationalized self-interest has trumped all previous cultural and religious solutions. The tragedy is beyond any kind of moral or political framework - it is neither good nor evil and harbors no hidden agenda. Sure it can be used as propoganda or for evil and has been so used for ages. The key is for individuals to know their self-interest and coordinate with other individuals to achieve mutually beneficial ends. This could lead to socialism or collectivism or capitalism or facism. However, those are human values and behaviors that are plugged into the game. If everyone is convinced that becoming part of a totalitarian wprld government is the best for their individual or collective self-interst and they acquiese to the institutions that enforce that outcome - voila, one world tyranny. This is not the fault of Hardin or Nash but of ourselves and our leaders that convince that this is the world we want.

For those harkening back to a simpler time, I'm afraid the past wasn't even the past. The outcomes that the commons produced were often irrational and barbaric - burning witches, fighting outsiders, religious wars. This is the "time out of mind" solution of culture and religion and the black lodges seek to recreate this reality today. As a species we have already bitten the apple and it is our responsibility to ourselves to understand and communicate what our self-interest is and what will be the probable outcomes of our individual and collective actions. Game theory provides an analytic rubric to evaluate how shit might possiblely play out.

I will end with my favorite scene from the film, Network. (I'd post the clip but I'm not so "techwise")

Arthur Jensen: I started as a salesman, Mr. Beale. I sold sewing machines and automobile parts, hair brushes and electronic equipment.
[puts arm around Beale's shoulders]

Arthur Jensen: They say I can sell anything. I'd like to try to sell something to *you*.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Arthur Jensen: [bellowing] You have meddled with the primal forces of nature, Mr. Beale, and I won't have it! Is that clear? You think you've merely stopped a business deal. That is not the case! The Arabs have taken billions of dollars out of this country, and now they must put it back! It is ebb and flow, tidal gravity! It is ecological balance! You are an old man who thinks in terms of nations and peoples. There are no nations. There are no peoples. There are no Russians. There are no Arabs. There are no third worlds. There is no West. There is only one holistic system of systems, one vast and immane, interwoven, interacting, multivariate, multinational dominion of dollars. Petro-dollars, electro-dollars, multi-dollars, reichmarks, rins, rubles, pounds, and shekels. It is the international system of currency which determines the totality of life on this planet. That is the natural order of things today. That is the atomic and subatomic and galactic structure of things today! And YOU have meddled with the primal forces of nature, and YOU...WILL...ATONE!
Arthur Jensen: [calmly] Am I getting through to you, Mr. Beale? You get up on your little twenty-one inch screen and howl about America and democracy. There is no America. There is no democracy. There is only IBM, and ITT, and AT&T, and DuPont, Dow, Union Carbide, and Exxon. Those *are* the nations of the world today. What do you think the Russians talk about in their councils of state, Karl Marx? They get out their linear programming charts, statistical decision theories, minimax solutions, and compute the price-cost probabilities of their transactions and investments, just like we do. We no longer live in a world of nations and ideologies, Mr. Beale. The world is a college of corporations, inexorably determined by the immutable bylaws of business. The world is a business, Mr. Beale. It has been since man crawled out of the slime. And our children will live, Mr. Beale, to see that . . . perfect world . . . in which there's no war or famine, oppression or brutality. One vast and ecumenical holding company, for whom all men will work to serve a common profit, in which all men will hold a share of stock. All necessities provided, all anxieties tranquilized, all boredom amused. And I have chosen you, Mr. Beale, to preach this evangel.

Howard Beale: Why me?

Arthur Jensen: Because you're on television, dummy. Sixty million people watch you every night of the week, Monday through Friday.
Howard Beale: I have seen the face of God.
Arthur Jensen: You just might be right, Mr. Beale.
User avatar
exojuridik
 
Posts: 258
Joined: Tue May 20, 2008 9:40 pm
Location: South of No North
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby wintler2 » Fri Aug 29, 2008 2:51 am

Great essay, 'its the assumptions, stupid!'
Searcher08 wrote:..It was interesting to read the example from Engels from an organisational design point of view, as the community itself had self-organised the feedback loops needed to address the problem.
I believe we can and must relearn how to do that, Law was never an adequate substitute. Some households manage to get along happily most of the time, some neighbours stay friends thru all seasons, its not rocket science, its usually much harder, but peace demands it.
"Wintler2, you are a disgusting example of a human being, the worst kind in existence on God's Earth. This is not just my personal judgement.." BenD

Research question: are all god botherers authoritarians?
User avatar
wintler2
 
Posts: 2884
Joined: Sun Nov 12, 2006 3:43 am
Location: Inland SE Aus.
Blog: View Blog (0)

Postby exojuridik » Fri Aug 29, 2008 12:32 pm

This essay probably annoys me more than it should but in my mind in reflects why the left is doomed which makes me both angry and sad. At its core the "tragedy of the commons" is not an ideological position but an expression of how power manifests itself amid competing interests. It is a tool which has been used very successfully by the PTB to advance a set of policies that are destroying the planet and the human race. However, for the left to ignore or deride the tool and not the craftsmen is akin to dismissing a geometric proof because you don't like the asthethtic arrangement of shapes in a work of art. Or disliking the laws of thermodynamics because it is too conservative in your mind.


My other problem with the essay and the responses is the glorification of past societies/cultures. There is a reason these societies no longer exist. It is historically suspect to assume that proto-modern people in Europe resolved their conflicts in such a nonwasteful and cooperative manner. first, in a world of about a half a billion they had more resources and were less restrained in the choices they made. Moreover, one can look at the literature and stories from the time and see that they weren't all enlightened decision-makers.

Hardin simply ignored what actually happens in a real commons: self-regulation by the communities involved. One such process was described years earlier in Friedrich Engels’ account of the “mark”, the form taken by commons-based communities in parts of pre-capitalist Germany:

“[T]he use of arable and meadowlands was under the supervision and direction of the community …

“Just as the share of each member in so much of the mark as was distributed was of equal size, so was his share also in the use of the ‘common mark’. The nature of this use was determined by the members of the community as a whole. …

“At fixed times and, if necessary, more frequently, they met in the open air to discuss the affairs of the mark and to sit in judgment upon breaches of regulations and disputes concerning the mark.” (Engels 1892)


What Engel's historiography ignores is the fact that there was trechery, doubling dealing and the stoning of heretics in these communities as well. Just look at the stories of the Brothers Grimm to see how cooperative and kind hearted these communities were. The whole thousand year legacy of burning heretics and witches stems in large part from ignorant commuities attempting to control their environment. The rise of facism and lutheranism were two solutions these volk supported.

In all societies individuals act as quasi-rational self-interest maximizers - culture/religion may provide the context and values that define this self-interest but doesn't change the underlying dilemma of coming up with cooperative strategies in the face of a dilemma of shared (and diminishing resources).

Hardin’s argument started with the unproven assertion that herders always want to expand their herds: “It is to be expected that each herdsman will try to keep as many cattle as possible on the commons… As a rational being, each herdsman seeks to maximize his gain.”

In short, Hardin’s conclusion was predetermined by his assumptions. “It is to be expected” that each herder will try to maximise the size of their herd — and each one does exactly that. It’s a circular argument that proves nothing.


No- Hardin isn't saying that each herdsman will act as a capitalist in this situation - If the herdsman acted as capitalist socio-paths, it is likely that the community would sanction that behavior and he would be condemned as being ungodly. This is an example of an institutional response and is still subject to the level of analysis Hardin describes. Communities are made up of individual actors. Thus the larger social dynamics are amenable to an indvidual level of analysis. Even Marx used this to explain why the interests of individuals were best served by class politics.

Overall, article's argument confuses the tragedy's analysis of the problem for the very problem the tragedy describes and the capitalist solution that was imposed.

Seriously, one can not underestimate the importance that a game theory has played in the world over the last 50 years. It has been used to tremedous value by world's elite to understand and control the game. There is a reason that this is taugfht in academic and professional programmes the world over - and it has little to do with brainwashing but rather showing the state of the art of our understanding of individual and collective behavior. If the left actually tackled these ideas they could similarly show how cooperative behavior can be better and more justly maintained.

Unfortunately, the left has eschewed it because they mistakenly believe that it doesn't comport with their view of humanity. In response I would suggest: 1. Game theory is not a normative theory - it just states when people are hungry they will eat; 2. Game theory is not a total theory but merely an analytic tool focusing on why individual choose to cooperate or not. Any macrotheory of society needs to take individual motive into account. after all we are all individuals before anything else. 3. sorry, but life doen't comport with my rosy theory of humanity either but here we are and we need to find rational solutions - attacking the wizards won't help anyone. Altruism is often the most rational choice of all.


Thank you for indulging me
User avatar
exojuridik
 
Posts: 258
Joined: Tue May 20, 2008 9:40 pm
Location: South of No North
Blog: View Blog (0)

Re: Debunking the `Tragedy of the Commons'

Postby stickdog99 » Mon Jul 11, 2011 12:38 pm

So did Native Americans actually try to live in harmony with the land around them or is that just a stupid liberal myth?
stickdog99
 
Posts: 6608
Joined: Tue Jul 12, 2005 5:42 am
Blog: View Blog (0)

Next

Return to General Discussion

Who is online

Users browsing this forum: No registered users and 140 guests